Engendering economics: new perspectives on women, work, and demographic change
p. 27-53
Note de l’auteur
Ce texte est repris ici avec la permission de la Banque Mondiale et a été publié dans "the annual World Bank Conference on Development" en 1995. En outre, traduit partiellement en français il est édité dans l'ouvrage Nancy Folbre, De la différence des sexes en économie politique, Éditions Des femmes, Paris, 1997, pp. 163-205.
Texte intégral
Rent-seeking coalitions based on gender create a gender bias in social institutions that influences market outcomes. How does economic development, which involves substantial relocation of economic functions from the family to the market and the state, affect the behavior of gender coalitions and the evolution of gender bias? Economists will not be able to adequately answer this question until they develop a broader research agenda and begin to collect more systematic data on institutional bias, the organization of nonmarket work, and the distribution of resources within the family.
engender:. 1. To give rise to. 2. To procreate. American Heritage Dictionary, Third edition
1Gender is now a popular, indeed indispensable, word in the development vocabulary. Most major international organizations, including the United Nations and the World Bank, have special units devoted to research and policy formulation on women’s issues. A growing official literature describes the importance of moving from models of "women in development" toward models of "gender and development," signaling a new emphasis on analyzing men’s roles as well as women’s1. A widespread consensus on the benefits of investing in women’s education has radically altered public policy in many parts of the world. Yet discussions of gender have remained segregated within special reports or specific policy initiatives, having relatively little impact on the mainstream discourse of development economics.
2There are many good reasons to focus on women. Women generally have lower incomes and less leisure time than men, and seldom have equal opportunities to develop their capabilities. Investments in women’s human capital typically yield a greater rate of return in labor productivity, child health, and family welfare than investments in men’s human capital (Subbarao & Raney, 1993). But apart from these practical benefits lies the possibility that the growing literature on women’s productive and reproductive work will offer important insights into the development process itself. "Engendering" economics – forcing it to explain the role gender plays in economic life – could help us better understand the evolution of social institutions and how they shape market outcomes.
3This article uses the concepts of the new institutional economics to illustrate differing approaches to women and development and to explain the theoretical significance of recent empirical research on women, work, and demographic change. The central hypothesis is that rent-seeking coalitions based on gender create a significant gender bias in social institutions, which strongly influence market outcomes. In turn, economic development, which involves a substantial relocation of economic functions from the family to the market and the state, affects the behavior of gender coalitions and the evolution of gender bias. This process could be better understood if economists paid more attention to institutional bias, the organization of nonmarket work, and the distribution of resources within the family. These issues are explored by considering four separate but related topics: property rights over land; explicit and implicit contracts governing intrafamily distribution; other institutional influences on the labor market, including government policies toward benefits and pensions; and estimates of the value of nonmarket work.
Gender Bias and Distributional Coalitions
In most cases, people do not perceive themselves to be rent seekers… Anne Krueger (1974)
4Much of the recent research on women, gender, and development focuses on gender bias, a term used to convey the notion that social institutions do not treat men and women in a welfare-neutral way. The problem emphasized is almost always male bias, and explanations for this bias fall into two categories (Kabeer, 1994; Moser, 1993). The women in development approach, the first to emerge in the literature, is an application of modernization theory. It treats the marginalization of women during development as an oversight that can be remedied by better incorporating them in the market economy (Boserup, 1970; Rogers, 1980)2. From this perspective gender bias reflects outdated norms and values that are no longer functional for society. The favored prescription is to invest more in women’s human capital. Emphasis is placed on the large gains in overall efficiency that can result from a reduction in sex discrimination. Women’s position in industrial countries such as the United States is held up as a model for women in developing countries.
5The gender and development approach is less optimistic. It emphasizes the persistent, structural character of inequality between men and women (Benería & Sen, 1981; Sen & Grown, 1987; Kabeer, 1994). Merely incorporating women into the development process will not improve their welfare – the process itself must be modified. But this modification will meet resistance from men because it will entail a redistribution of income along gender lines that may not be fully compensated by gains in overall efficiency. The position of women in industrial countries is not inspiring because they remain disadvantaged, particularly regarding the distribution of the costs of children (Folbre, 1994).
6Although much has been written on the distinction between these two approaches, their theoretical underpinnings remain largely unexplored. Advocates of the women in development approach tend to employ quantitative methods, particularly human capital models. Advocates of the gender and development approach often rely on descriptive data and historical narrative, with liberal applications of the word "empowerment." Both sides of this debate can be reinterpreted using the concepts of the new institutional economics. Indeed, examined this way, the gender and development literature provides strong support for the institutionalist theory of rent-seeking coalitions.
An Institutionalist Primer
7The new institutional economics focuses on the evolution of social institutions, which form the context in which individual decisions are made (North, 1981, 1990; Olson, 1982; Hodgson, 1987). Broadly defined, social institutions are means of social coordination, ranging from organizations such as the firm, the family, and the state to the political rules and social norms that help such organizations function3. Their stability, efficiency, and incentive structures influence the process of economic development (Williamson, 1995) and the empowerment of social groups designated by gender, nation, race, class, or other dimensions of collective identity (Folbre, 1994).
8What forces shape the evolution of social institutions? In answering this question most institutional economists stress the dictates of efficiency enforced by the pressures of competition. In the long run the social institutions that provide the most efficient solution to coordination problems prevail. Coase’s (1960) concise formulation of this approach provided a basis for later applications to the family (Becker, 1981) and the firm (Williamson, 1985). In applying this perspective to economic history, North widened its purview to the analysis of social norms (1981, 1990).
9The transaction costs perspective maintains that current social institutions may not be perfectly optimal. Some are at risk of being eliminated by heightened competition. Some may be adjusting to changes in relative prices and incomes with an uncomfortable lag because of inertial tendencies. Cultural norms, in particular, cannot be changed overnight. But despite these imperfections and lags, social institutions are evolving toward an efficient, Parieto-optimal equilibrium. This theoretical perspective implicitly underlies much of the women in development literature.
10Its basic reasoning runs: a gender wage differential emerges in traditional agrarian economies partly because men have greater physical strength, which is an especially important factor of production (Goldin, 1990). Also, the high fertility rates that characterize agrarian economies make women dependent on male support. Social institutions, including social norms, both reflect and enforce male dominance. In the course of economic development, however, technological change increases the importance of mental skills relative to physical strength and encourages fertility decline (Becker, 1981; Schultz, 1993). This change destabilizes the traditional gender division of labor: male dominance becomes less efficient. But, traditional social norms (as well as mistaken development policy) may impede the adjustment to modern egalitarian norms.
11An alternative view, which might be termed the "distributional conflict paradigm", insists on the importance of processes of collective aggrandizement. As Knight (1992:19) puts it, "the ongoing development of social institutions is not best explained as a Pareto-superior response to collective goals or benefits but, rather, as a byproduct of conflicts over distributional gains." Social institutions such as the firm or the family may enhance efficiency, but they may also serve the interests of particular groups. Obstacles to social change are not only manifestations of lagged adjustment, they often reflect active resistance on the part of powerful groups, who may be willing to pay a price, in lower efficiency, for continued control over a disproportionate share of output.
Gender-Based Conflict
12The best known proponents of the distributional conflict paradigm have shied away from any direct consideration of gender. Olson (1982) describes how distributional coalitions can clog the process of efficient allocation but focuses on interest groups rather than groups that individuals do not choose to join4. He never considers the possibility that men and women might be groups contending over the distribution of resources. Neither Buchanan (1980) nor Krueger (1974) describe men as a group that might engage in rent seeking through the state. But there is no reason why this theoretical framework cannot be applied to groups based on gender.
13Men and women are not literally interest groups. Most individuals do not choose their gender in the same way that they join a club. But they often identify with others of their same gender, define common interests, and engage in collective action, ranging from participation in explicit political activity to less formal efforts to defend or develop advantageous social norms. A large body of feminist theory, as well as much of the gender and development literature reviewed in this article, illustrates how male collective action has led to the development of social institutions that give men important economic advantages in control over property, income, and labor. It also shows that women have increasingly begun to engage in collective action to contest and modify such institutions (see Folbre, 1994).
14There is much to be gained, however, by moving beyond purely descriptive accounts to more analytical efforts to test the hypothesis that gender bias reflects the rent-seeking efforts of gender coalitions. More open debate over this issue could help overcome a certain reticence evident in the literature today. Among policymakers, at least, there is a strong tendency to avoid consideration of social conflict, partly out of fear of intensifying it. The women in development approach, with its "everybody gains" emphasis on increasing efficiency, is especially appealing to policymakers and multilateral institutions (Klasen, 1993; Kardam, 1990).
15But policymakers could benefit from a more forthright analysis of the distributional gains and losses that policies impose on distinct social groups. One of the insights of the new institutional economics is that rent-seeking coalitions are often successful at blocking changes that could benefit society as a whole, partly because of the difficulty of devising and enforcing the kinds of side payments that could partially compensate for distributional losses (Libecap, 1989). More open consideration of distributional conflict, in other words, may help resolve rather than intensify it.
16At the same time, devoting more attention to the new institutional economics could encourage gender and development theorists to move beyond a documentation of inequality to an analysis of its functional implications. Unpleasant though the political implications may seem, hierarchy and inequality may serve economic functions by lowering transaction costs and solving coordination problems. More egalitarian alternatives are unlikely to be successful unless they are at least as efficient. For instance, challenges to traditional male authority must be accompanied by alternative ways of enforcing familial obligations and encouraging commitments to children. The experience of industrial countries suggests that the weakening of patriarchal relations within the family is often accompanied by a weakening of intrafamily income flows and growth in poverty among mothers and children living on their own (Folbre, 1994).
17Finally, more serious efforts to examine gender-based conflicts could address a serious theoretical weakness in the distributional conflict paradigm – the difficulty of specifying the relationship among different types of social groups and resulting overlaps among different types of rent-seeking activity. There is a clear analogy between forms of collective aggrandizement based on gender and those based on other dimensions of collective identity, such as nation or race or class. Men often gang up on women. Likewise, men and women in strong groups often gang up on men and women in weak groups.
18Women’s best interests are not always best served by gender solidarity alone. As many scholars and activists from developing countries have emphasized, women identify themselves as members of coalitions based on nation, race, or class that claim their allegiance (Mohanty, 1991; Agarwal, 1994b). The forms of inequality that women resist and the types of collective action that they engage in depend largely on specific political and historical circumstances. Research on the form, timing, and intensity of gender conflict in different countries could help economists decipher the behavior of distributional coalitions in general.
Collective Action, Gender, and Property Rights
Please go and ask the sarkar [government] why when it distributes land we don’t get a title. Are we not peasants?
If my husband throws me out, where is my security?
West Bengali woman, cited in Agarwal (1994b)
19Economists emphasize the significant impact that property rights have on incentives to work, invest, and innovate (Libecap 1989). Yet relatively few have systematically examined gender-based differences in rights to land ownership. The gender and development literature offers evidence of such differences, which have strong implications not only for agricultural productivity but also for women’s bargaining position within the family and the labor market.
Land Ownership, Family Law, and Colonial Policies
20Property rights to land are bound to family law because most claims to property are earned through either inheritance or marriage. Analysis of these rights is complicated considerably by conflicting sets of laws (formal compared with customary, secular compared with religious) and large discrepancies between legal precepts and actual practices. Most of the detailed research on these issues has focused on Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, although there is some evidence from Latin America. In general, women have far less access to land than men and, largely as a result, less access to credit and technical extension services (Holt & Ribe, 1991; Staudt, 1978). Patriarchal rules of land transmission and ownership do not follow a market logic and certainly do not allow women to compete on even ground with men. Although they may have some functional logic, patriarchal rules also enable men to extract monopolistic rents from women – not in the literal sense of charging them money, but in the broader sense of reducing their income per hour worked. Patriarchal rules establish the male head of household as the residual claimant of the household enterprise and provide economic incentives to maximize his share of output and leisure (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972). The extent to which these incentives are countervailed by familial altruism is empirically uncertain (this point is made in Becker, 1981, and later in this article).
21Traditional tribal law in most areas of Sub-Saharan Africa accorded access to land based on relationship to a kinship group. While women enjoyed the right to use land, protected by custom, their formal rights were almost always subordinate to those of men (Martin & Hashi, 1992a). Despite enormous diversity among tribes, most women did not have inheritance rights to a father’s or a husband’s property. This gender bias was intensified and, in a sense, homogenized, by colonial policies that imposed privatization. Land titles were almost always handed out to male heads of household (Martin & Hashi, 1992a).
22Today, women in Sub-Saharan Africa often do not have formal ownership rights to land, even if they provide the bulk of agricultural labor (Martin & Hashi, 1992c; Blackden & Morris-Hughes, 1993). The disjuncture between ownership and labor has been heightened by extensive male outmigration. But this problem cannot be explained as a simple legacy of the past; relatively recent policies set by independent African governments have reinforced male property rights. For instance, the Zimbabwe constitution of 1980 did not grant women legal guarantees of joint ownership, inheritance from husbands, or even control over earnings, despite the efforts of women’s organizations (Cheater, l981). Zimbabwean women have benefited little from the modest resettlement program, which is based on government purchases of land from white farmers. Only male settlers who are married or widowed and female widows with dependents have been eligible to receive land – women on their own, whether deserted, divorced, or widowed, have been excluded. As a result the economic position of widows and orphans is worse than what it was in traditional rural settings, in which the husband’s kin assumed some responsibility for them (Munachonga, l988).
23In South Asia women have seldom worked as independent farmers with separate plots or crops. But they often provide agricultural labor, and land ownership is a crucial determinant of their economic welfare. More is known about the history and evolution of gendered land rights in this region than in any other area of the world because of the pioneering work of Agarwal (1994a, 1995). The precolonial period was characterized by considerable regional variation, with some communities in northeastern and southern India and in Sri Lanka practicing matrilineal or bilateral inheritance. Agarwal argues that women had greater bargaining power in the family and greater freedom of movement in these areas, though they seldom enjoyed any of the prerogatives of controlling or managing land (1994a).
24As in Africa, colonialism and national integration imposed more uniform standards of inheritance, which weakened women’s access to land in many respects. Privatization itself led to a reduction in access to resources such as fodder and fuel, with a concomitant rise in the amount of time and effort women were forced to devote to meeting their households’ subsistence needs.
25Legal reforms adopted after the demise of formal colonialism furthered women’s legal rights to land. In India the Hindu Succession Act of 1956 gave daughters, widows, and mothers of intestate men rights equal to those of sons. In Pakistan the West Pakistan Muslim Personal Law Application Act of 1962 legally entitled Muslim women to inherit agricultural property. But even within these reformed systems, gender bias has been exacerbated by enforcement problems, particularly in regions governed by customary law (Agarwal, 1994a). In addition, government-sponsored land reform programs typically distributed land to male heads of households. As a result few women own land and only a very few exercise effective, independent control over it.
26The picture for Latin America is remarkably similar: although in many communities women have enjoyed bilateral inheritance longer than in South Asia, they remain far less likely than men to own land. Most reforms implemented after World War II redistributed property that was under oligarchical control to individual men, with little provision for wive’s co-ownership and active disregard for single women and those heading their own households (Deere & León, 1987). More recent land reforms in Honduras were not so egregiously biased. But although single women were legally eligible to receive redistributed land, stricter conditions were imposed on them than on men (Safilios-Rothschild, 1988).
Male Control of Property: An Institutional Explanation
27Why is women’s lack of access to property a characteristic shared across regions? It reflects men’s control over political and legal institutions, which have enforced patriarchal marriage and kinship systems (Martin & Hashi, 1992b). In most countries women have only begun to participate in the formal specification of property rights. Social systems based on a male monopoly over property emerged in many different contexts and prevailed, unchallenged, for long periods of time. Why?
28Part of the answer may lie in an institutional logic linking relationships between men and women to those between parents and children. In traditional patriarchal regimes land ownership gave fathers considerable leverage over children and allowed them to expect at least some benefits in the form of labor contributions and support in old age (Caldwell, 1982). Although this system raised the economic incentives for coercive forms of control over women, it also established an implicit rate of return for women’s reproductive labor within the family economy. Men who abused or neglected their children or the mothers of their children lowered their own economic welfare. In the aggregate, male control over property provided an enforcement mechanism that created incentives for paternal care of dependents, with pronatalist, but also profamily effects5.
29One conspicuous side effect of such an incentive structure is relative neglect of female children, often motivated by institutional arrangements (such as patrilineal property transmission and dowry) that make it easier for families to gain economically from sons than from daughters. But, ironically, the existence of such gender differentials testifies to the larger influence of pecuniary incentives – probably operating through social norms rather than through actual parental calculations – and suggests that the reduction of these incentives through loss of male control over land may contribute to neglect of both sons and daughters. Neglect is especially likely if there is little cultural or technical support for family planning and if the economic costs of children are rising more rapidly than fathers anticipated.
30With the increase in individually based employment and declining farm sizes, obligations to care for kin become increasingly dependent on altruism. Men have less to gain from children’s labor and from fulfilling responsibilities to mothers and children. Maximizing fertility becomes a less attractive economic strategy, and family commitments become more costly. Also, development typically reduces access to common property rights6. Under these circumstances the negative distributional consequences of exclusive male property rights become more salient for women and children, who become dependent on transfers that are increasingly contingent and unreliable. Furthermore, as women shift more of their time away from childcare and household services and into work outside the home, male monopolies over property become increasingly costly to them.
31These adverse effects are exacerbated by the economic and demographic trends characteristic of most developing countries: the growth of employment outside agriculture has been relatively slow, and the agricultural labor force is becoming increasingly feminized in South Asia and Latin America (Agarwal, 1994a; Deere, 1995). Both male outmigration and cultural modernization lead to increased rates of desertion, separation, and divorce. And women become increasingly dependent on land ownership (even if only a small parcel) for economic security. Furthermore, several studies suggest that adult children’s remittances to their parents are a positive function of parental asset ownership (Hoddinot, 1992; Lucas & Stark, 1985). Thus elderly women without land rights may be particularly vulnerable.
32By lowering the returns to their labor, the absence of property rights also lowers women’s reservation wage in the labor market. As women are becoming increasingly dependent on their individually earned wage, it is hardly surprising that they are beginning to realize that they need rights to family property. Women in many countries are increasingly engaging in forms of collective action designed to enhance such rights. And if they are not successful, their economic position is likely to worsen.
Family Law, Bargaining, and Intrafamily Distribution
33Another set of nonmarket institutions has a substantial impact on the welfare of women: the claims of mothers and children on the income of fathers. Such claims, which can be considered both property rights and human rights, are shaped by explicit contracts (defined by law) and implicit contracts (defined by social norms). Historically, these contracts have been defined largely by men and have given men important benefits, which can be thought of as monopoly rents.
34The traditional neoclassical theory of marriage holds that both partners benefit from efficiency gains if men specialize in market production and women in childrearing (Becker, 1981). Yet no major tradition of family law actually guarantees married women’s claims on their husbands’ income stream (Glendon, 1989). The transfers they receive depend almost entirely on the altruism of family members with access to market earnings. Fathers are expected and exhorted to provide a basic level of subsistence for mothers and children. But if they fail to do so, they seldom receive formal punishment.
35Ten years ago the claim that there might be less-than-perfect altruism in the family, leading to significant welfare inequalities there, was considered far-fetched. Since then, however, publication of several (though a still relatively small number of) empirical studies has shifted the burden of proof to those who assume that the family can be treated as an undifferentiated unit (Alderman and others 1995; Dwyer & Bruce, 1988; Schultz, 1990; Thomas, 1990). The traditional neoclassical model of joint utility and perfect altruism in the family has been supplemented, if not supplanted, by a new generation of bargaining power models.
36Most important from an institutionalist perspective are models that show how property rights, contractual obligations, and social norms external to the household set the stage for unequal distributional outcomes. McElroy (1990) clearly demonstrates how "extra-environmental parameters" set by social policy influence a woman’s fallback position (her income should she leave the household). Lundberg and Pollak (1993) incorporate cultural norms by arguing that the traditional division of labor and income is the fallback position for men and women bargaining over an alternative allocation. Sen (1990) observes that social norms may prevent women from noticing, much less resisting, inequality in the family.
37Because men enjoy gains or rents as a result of extra-environmental parameters, they are motivated to act collectively to maintain those most advantageous to them. At the same time extra-environmental parameters motivate women to act collectively to improve their bargaining position within the household. In particular, women’s groups in northwest Europe, the United States, and Latin America have consistently fought for improved specification of maintenance and child support responsibilities (Folbre, 1994).
38Another legal issue that has received considerable attention is the enforcement of legal rights to physical safety. A recent World Bank study finds that rape, domestic violence, and sexual abuse impose major health costs, even in countries with seemingly strict legal protections (Heise, Pitanguy, & Germain, 1994). Women are the primary victims; and when they respond with gender-based collective action, they often meet intense resistance. In 1968, for instance, women’s groups in Kenya supported the Marriage Bill, which would have made wife-beating a criminal offense. It was defeated by male parliamentarians on the grounds that wife-beating was a customary practice and the bill threatened to impose foreign values on traditional culture (Gage & Njogu, 1994). More recently, women in Latin America have developed women-only police stations, which facilitate reporting of domestic abuse (Heise, Pitanguy & Germain, 1994). Other community factors, such as the availability of public assistance for women, influence the probability that domestic violence will occur (Tauchen, Witte & Long, 1991).
39The explicit and implicit contracts that define the rights and responsibilities of family life vary considerably among cultures and regions. In Sub-Saharan Africa many traditions have militated against income pooling, and mothers have traditionally been expected to provide for themselves and their children. This expectation remains in force today. Particularly in polygynous unions, mothers pay a disproportionate share of child maintenance costs (Gage & Njogu, 1994). In most southern African countries maintenance laws are full of loopholes (Armstrong, 1992). About Ghana, Abu (1983: 161 – 62) writes, "the social forces constraining a man to look after his wife and children are relatively weak, and there is a considerable voluntary element in the arrangement." The economic consequences may not be negative as long as children are able to contribute to family income or the larger kinship unit is willing to help assume their costs. But as the demand for schooling increases along with school fees, the economic burden on mothers will rise.
40Laws and norms governing income pooling within the household are stronger in other regions of the world. But a considerable body of research documents substantial gender inequality. Many empirical studies confirm what might be termed "the good mother" hypothesis: women generally devote a far larger share of their income and earnings to family needs than do men (Benería & Roldán, 1987; Blumberg, 1989; Chant, 1991). Income that is controlled by women is more likely to be spent on children’s health and nutrition and less likely to be spent on alcohol and adult goods (Dwyer & Bruce, 1988; Hoddinott, Alderman & Haddad, forthcoming).
41Unequal distribution of resources to male and female children within the household is also significant. Inequalities vary by region. In South Asia there is considerable evidence of preference for sons (Rosenzweig & Schultz, 1982; Sen, 1988). In Brazil mothers may spend more on daughters, fathers more on sons (Thomas, 1990). In Sub-Saharan Africa boys and girls are treated fairly equally (Haddad & Reardon, 1993), possibly because brideprice rather than dowry customs are in effect.
Supporting Households Headed by Women
42An emphasis on intrahousehold allocation is misleading because it deflects attention from the high percentage of households with children but no adult male. In Kenya 24 percent of all households were headed by women in 1980. A rural income distribution survey conducted in Botswana in 1974 – 75 found that 28 percent of households were headed by women, with no adult male present (Koussoudji & Mueller, 1983). In rural India 30 – 35 percent of all households are headed by women (World Bank, 1991). In Ghana female-headed households rose from 22 percent to 29 percent between 1960 and 1987 – 88 (Lloyd & Gage-Brandon, 1993).
43Men may leave their households to search for higher-paying jobs and may remit large shares of their wage income. But the experiences of the United States and northwestern Europe suggest that female headship is often associated with the attenuation of income flows from men to women and children. Accurate data on the number of households economically maintained by women alone, which can be generated only through detailed household surveys, are a priority for future research (Folbre, 1990).
44Female headship does not necessarily increase economic vulnerability, as shown by studies of Brazil (Barros, Fox & Mendonca, 1993) and Jamaica (Louat, Grosh & van der Gaag, 1992).
45But women who are raising small children without the help of male income are at great risk economically, as are their children. The extensive data available for industrial countries show that these families are highly susceptible to poverty, even in countries that provide them with some public assistance (Folbre, 1994). Relatively little attention has been devoted to studies of their welfare in the developing world, although Desai (1991) found that children of single mothers in three Latin American countries (such as those born to women in consensual unions) were more like to be undernourished than those living with both parents.
46Family dissolution and out-of-wedlock births are extremely costly to mothers because prevailing family laws offer little protection. Only a few countries in northwestern Europe, most notably France and Sweden, have successfully developed mechanisms for enforcing child support. In the United States less than half of all mothers raising children on their own are awarded child support, and only about half of these (25 percent of the total) receive the full amount they are due. Moreover, the level of payments is low and has declined in recent years (Beller & Graham, 1993). In Japan a 1988 study revealed that only about 14 percent of divorced fathers made some kind of payment for their children (Goode, 1993).
47Little is known about enforcing child support in developing countries because data are not systematically collected. Indeed, data were not collected in the United States until 1980, when women’s groups successfully lobbied Congress to require the Census to conduct regular surveys. Women in developing countries have been less successful in raising the issue. In Kenya an affiliation act that would have required men to provide financial support for their children born out of wedlock was repealed in 1969 by an all-male assembly (Morgan, 1984). Ghana passed a decree in 1977 establishing family tribunals, but it had no discernible effect (Gage & Njogu, 1994). Even in Columbia and Peru, where many conspicuous forms of gender bias in family law were eliminated in the 1970s, mothers and children enjoy only a weak legal claim on fathers’ income (Ramirez, 1987). Evidence from Argentina suggests that paternal child support responsibilities are poorly enforced (Goode, 1993). Brachet-Marquez (1992) explains how and why the Mexican legal system makes it easy for men to avoid financial responsibility. A recent study of children born to adolescent Chilean women finds that 42 percent of the children have received no support from their fathers by the time they are six years old (Buvinic and others 1992). Jamaican law stipulates that children have a right to support from any coresident male, but actual contributions are small and intermittent (Bolles, 1986)7.
48The willingness and ability of some fathers to "divorce" their children without penalty makes mothers aware of the risks of abandonment and puts them in a weak bargaining position in the family. After many decades of focusing on mother-child relationships, social scientists are just beginning to explore fathers’ roles. Engle and Breaux (1994) ask whether or not there is a "father instinct." Katzman (1992) of the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America speculates that men are suffering from a loss of self-esteem due to their loss of power within the family.
49An alternative explanation follows from the observation that most family law was forged during an era in which children provided at least some economic benefits to fathers, reinforcing cultural norms of paternal responsibility. Although such traditional circumstances did not guarantee fully adequate protection for dependents, they may have served better than more modern arrangements. Economic development raises the costs of having children by increasing their educational requirements and their economic independence. Adjustments in the form of lower fertility rates are lagged and uneven. As a result development often increases the economic stress imposed on families with children.
Sorting the Responsibilities of Mothers and Fathers
50Whether due to biology or culture or some combination, mothers seem to have stronger commitments to children than do fathers. Mothers are thus less affected than fathers by the increasing economic incentives to default on the traditional explicit and implicit contracts of parenthood. These incentives are compounded by economic problems, such as unemployment and famine, and may also be exacerbated by mobility. Migration is a male survival strategy that is often synonymous with desertion (Elson, 1992).
51This analysis does not imply that economic development always leads to family breakdown or to reductions in paternal commitments. Rather, it suggests that development increases the risk of certain kinds of "family failure," which we might think of as analogous to market failure or state failure, and requires institutional adaptation.
52Indeed, adaptation is already under way in the form of collective efforts to revise and reform family laws and norms. But it is important to note that men as a group have less to gain economically than women and children from reforms that enforce paternal responsibilities. A theory of distributional coalitions leads us to expect that women’s groups seeking such reforms will meet considerable resistance from men – behavior that we have observed (Kerr, 1993).
53Appreciation of the complexities of gender-based conflict also offers an explanation of why women may not always favor cultural modernization – and may endorse fundamentalist forms of resistance to cultural change. Women confront a paradox: the same aspects of the development process that increase their economic independence as individuals (expansion of education and wage employment) increase their economic vulnerability as mothers. The relative size of these two effects is determined by the political context and pattern of economic development. And under certain circumstances women’s groups may correctly calculate that they have more to lose from male-dominated modernization than from male-dominated tradition.
54Whether this admittedly speculative analysis of the logic of women’s collective action is correct or not, the institutional framework determining family rights certainly affects both economic and demographic decisionmaking. Poor stipulation and enforcement of maintenance laws puts the marital partner who specializes in housework or childrearing at a disadvantage. Lack of protection against domestic violence puts physically weaker family members at risk. These failings encourage men to claim a disproportionate share of family income and leisure and lower the economic costs of children to fathers. More equal sharing of these costs would give men a greater financial stake in limiting their own fertility (Armstrong, 1992). Finally, failure to enforce child support responsibilities on the part of fathers increases the economic incentives for paternal desertion.
Gender and the Labor Market
55Inferior property rights and poorly enforced claims on family members lower women’s share of family wealth and income relative to men’s. One result is a reduction in women’s reservation wages, increasing their willingness to accept low-paying jobs. Yet these institutional factors have been largely ignored by the conventional economic literature on gender wage differentials, which focuses primarily on the individual characteristics of male and female wage earners. This literature also sidesteps the issue of cultural norms, which may generate differences in preference for wage employment between men and women.
56Empirical research based on human capital models has made important contributions, clarifying the limits of employer-based discrimination and demonstrating the implications of differences in men’s and women’s access to education. But human capital models fall far short of providing a complete picture of gender inequality in the labor market. In addition to ignoring the asymmetry of rights and responsibilities that affects the supply of women’s labor, these models provide little insight into the demand side of the labor market.
Employer Discrimination
57Significant gender-based wage differentials characterize labor markets in every country in the world: women earn, on average, 60 – 70 percent as much as men (World Bank, 1995). These differences would be more extreme if wage data included women engaged in unpaid family work and work in the informal sector. Part of the gender wage differential can be explained by differences in levels of education, often a result of public policies that have emphasized educating men more than women. Investments in women’s education increase their earnings and their productivity, generating a big payoff for the economy as a whole (Subbarao & Raney, 1993; King & Hill, 1993).
58Evidence of discrimination, narrowly defined as lower wages for individuals with the same education and experience, is mixed. Of the six studies of wage discrimination in Latin America and Africa included in Birdsall and Sabot (1991), only two provide strong evidence of gender wage discrimination. But most of the twenty-one studies of Latin America included in Psacharopoulos and Tzannatos (1992) find a substantial gender gap in wages that cannot be explained by human capital differences. The U. S. experience clearly shows that women’s increased access to education does not eliminate the gender wage differential (Goldin, 1990). The discriminatory behavior of both private employers and the state plays an important role.
59Differences in the demand for men’s and women’s labor may reflect a taste for discrimination, or a cost-minimizing statistical discrimination, based on the presumption that women are less committed to the labor force than men and should therefore be limited to low-skilled jobs for which performance does not suffer from high turnover. Anker and Hein (1985) report that employers often explicitly express a preference for male workers and think that turnover among women is higher than it actually is. In any case women are more likely to show high turnover rates if they are restricted to relatively unskilled, poorly paid jobs.
Policy-Based Discrimination
60The demand for women’s labor is also limited by policy-based or public discrimination. Many public regulations increase the relative price of women’s labor by imposing the cost of maternity benefits or childcare on individual employers, despite the fact that the International Labor Office’s Maternity Protection Convention stipulates that individual employers should not be individually liable for the cost of maternity benefits (Anker & Hein, 1985; Winter, 1994). As a result many employers hire fewer women than they otherwise might; some even require women to provide medical certification that they are not pregnant.
61In Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union both state and private enterprises once provided large subsidies for maternity leave and childcare. These subsidies have now been reduced substantially. Privatization has created an economic environment in which firms that continue to provide such benefits may not be able to compete successfully with those that do not. Research on the effects of privatization on female workers has produced mixed results. Women in eastern Germany have had a greater risk of losing their jobs and a lower probability of finding new ones (Bellmann and others, 1992; Maier, 1993). Women make up a disproportionate number of the registered unemployed in Russia, Poland, and the Czech Republic (Klasen, 1993; Levin, 1993; Commander, Liberman & Yemtsov, 1993). In Slovakia the gender wage differential declined between 1988 and 1991 (Ham, Svejnar & Terrell, 1995). And in Slovenia men have suffered greater job and wage losses than women, possibly because women are, on average, slightly better educated (Abraham & Vodopivec, 1993; Orazem & Vodopivec, 1994).
62Unfortunately, similar attention has not been devoted to an empirical analysis of differences between mothers and nonmothers in the workplace – women responsible for the care of young children or other dependents are far more likely than other workers to be affected by the loss of public support for family labor. If these women drop out of the labor force in disproportionate numbers because of policy changes, they exacerbate the selectivity bias in measures of women’s wages. It is difficult to find any systematic account of actual reductions in childcare, family allowance, and parental leave provisions in recently privatized economics, although many scholars have commented on such reductions (Fong & Paul, 1992; Levin, 1993). Nor is much known about the de jure or de facto structure of worker’s rights, including protections against overt discrimination.
63Another topic of serious concern in both industrial and developing economies is the gender bias built into the structure of benefits based on wage employment, such as social security programs. Disproportionately concentrated in part-time, intermittent, and informal employment, women are less likely than men to work in jobs that are covered by benefits. Their claims on family benefits are typically attenuated by desertion or divorce. Married female employees pay the same taxes but receive lower benefits than their male counterparts: in both Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa survivors’ benefits are given to widows of covered male workers, but strict conditions are imposed on survivors’ benefits given to widowers of covered female workers (widowers must be dependent invalids in order to qualify). In other words the programs transfer more income to an eligible man with a spouse than to an eligible woman with a spouse. And although the retirement age is often lower for women than for men, benefits are lower as well. Family allowances give male workers an additional stipend if they have a dependent wife, but female workers do not receive extra amounts to help them pay for the cost of childcare (Folbre, 1993b).
64These types of gender bias in employment benefits violate International Labor Office guidelines, as well as the United Nations’ Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination Against Women. Many individual countries also have laws against sex discrimination. But although these regulations may affect policies in the public sector (where women enjoy more and better-paid opportunities), they are seldom enforced in the private sector; imported standards are often incompatible with the local legal and political climate. For instance, Latin American legal systems generally disallow class action suits and do not permit judicial verdicts to influence future rulings (Winter, 1994). These regulations affect the collection of data and the level of enforcement. In the United States court cases and lawsuits have provided evidence of explicit sexual discrimination that would not otherwise have been revealed (Bergmann, 1986).
65There has been remarkably little analysis of the impact of public policies on women’s wages or employment in developing countries. Future research should attempt to quantify the impact of maternity-related legislation, which varies sufficiently among countries to provide a basis for comparison. The effect of antidiscrimination efforts could also be estimated, following the example set by Beller’s (1982) analysis of the impact of equal rights legislation on women’s pay in the United States.
66In general, export-oriented growth has been associated with increases in women’s employment in manufacturing (Joekes, 1987). In some countries, such as the Republic of Korea, gender discrimination has been used as a tool for increasing export competitiveness (Seguino, 1994). In others, such as Ireland, public policies have explicitly and successfully sought to increase male rather than female employment (Pyle, 1990).
67Gender-biased employment policies must be analyzed in the same terms as policies prescribing property and family rights – as an outcome of distributional conflict. In this case collective interests based on class as well as gender come into play: workers as a group benefit from protective legislation that helps them to care for their children. In a sense employers owe workers such assistance, because workers are producing the next generation’s labor force, often at considerable cost to their own standard of living. But if such assistance reinforces gender inequality, it assigns women a disproportionate share of the costs of parenthood.
68It is hardly surprising that policymakers and employers, who are predominantly male, seldom promote gender equality in the labor market beyond measures that have obvious, powerful efficiency effects, such as investing in women’s education. What is surprising is that they continue to ignore the limitations of the conventional male model of employment when throughout the world, women are becoming increasingly important labor force participants. Both family leave and family-based benefits could be provided on a gender-neutral basis. A shorter paid workday for both men and women could help individuals combine market work and family responsibilities over the life cycle.
An Institutionalist View of Childcare
69It is sometimes suggested that women simply have a greater preference for childcare than do men, and the utility that they gain represents a "compensating differential" for their greater susceptibility to poverty (Fuchs, 1988). One could argue, similarly, that differences in preference between genders account for a portion of the gender wage differential. And these differences may be at work, with somewhat reassuring consequences regarding the level of discrimination. But this argument hinges on the conventional neoclassical assumption that tastes and preferences are exogenously given.
70An institutionalist approach suggests that individual preferences are partially shaped by social norms, and social norms are in turn strongly influenced by the interests and power of distributional coalitions (Folbre, 1994). Thus as women gain collective power, they challenge and modify social norms of femininity that are costly to them. They may also challenge the traditional social construction of masculinity in ways that are threatening to men. "If women no longer want to take care of the kids," men may ask, "who will?" True — if feminine norms of familial altruism are substantially weakened and masculine norms of familial altruism remain unchanged, some countries may run into serious difficulties in taking care of children and other dependents.
71These are important issues, not only for relations between men and women, but also for relations between parents and nonparents. Public provision of childcare and assistance to parents would significantly increase overall labor productivity if productivity were defined — as the next section argues it should be – in terms that include the value of nonmarket inputs and outputs.
Household Production and Economic Growth
72Contemporary microeconomic theory explicitly recognizes the importance of nonmarket work, largely as a result of the pioneering work of Becker (1981). Many household surveys of developing countries, especially those oriented toward health, document the importance of labor and other inputs into household production. Yet macroeconomic theory ignores the nonmarket sector almost entirely. Despite the criticisms of conventional national income accounting articulated by Eisner (1989) and others, only a few countries in northwestern Europe are systematically imputing the value of nonmarket work.
73Some feminist theorists argue that national income accounts are, themselves, based on measures that evolved from accumulated gender bias (Waring, 1988; Folbre, 1991). Whether there is more resistance to change than might be expected from any challenge to a conventional paradigm is an issue for historians of economic thought. More important from the point of view of economic development are the consequences for assessing social welfare. These are profound, as Blackden and Morris-Hughes (1993: i) point out in a recent World Bank analysis of Sub-Saharan Africa:
"The structural presence of women in economic production is largely invisible and overlooked in the prevailing paradigm. This is turn leads to incomplete and partial evaluation of economic outcomes, including adjustment and its effects on the poor, and masks critical interlinkages and complementarities among sectors of economic activity and between the paid and unpaid economies. It also limits assessment of the likely and potential supply response in the economy."
74Current estimates suggest that the economic value of household production in most countries amounts to an additional 30 – 50 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), depending on the method of valuation used (Goldschmidt-Clermont, 1982).
Inaccurately Measuring Women’s Market Labor
75Accounting problems are threefold. First, conventional census and labor force surveys typically mismeasure the number of women working in the market, vitiating both cross-national comparisons and analyses of longitudinal trends. The conventional definition of labor force participation is based on full-time or close to full-time employment for wages or other market income. But women are likely to engage in part-time or periodic market work and still make important contributions to family income. The dichotomous "in or out" definition of a labor force participant fits men’s experience better than women’s. A better definition would rate both men and women along a spectrum of participation in market activities.
76The mismeasurement of women’s market activities in the late nineteenth-and early twentieth-century United States has been well documented (Folbre & Abel, 1989). This problem is even more serious in developing countries, where both the informal and agricultural sectors absorb a large amount of women’s labor (Benería, 1981, 1982, 1992). The 1981 Indian census recorded only 14 percent of adult women participating in the market labor force; contemporaneous surveys yielded a much higher estimate of 39 percent (World Bank, 1991).
Valuing Nonmarket Labor
77A second problem concerns the treatment of labor time devoted to housework and childcare, which is recognized as a crucial input on the microeconomic level but considered macroeconomically unproductive. Human capital theorists do not insist on official imputations of the value of nonmarket inputs into human capital. As Elson (1992: 34) puts it, "Macromodels appear to treat human resources as a nonproduced means of production like land." Most economists are reluctant to consider childcare a productive activity. Indeed, a great deal of intellectual attention has been devoted to demarcating a boundary between domestic and nondomestic activities, even though economic theory suggests no distinction between the two (Beneriá, 1992).
78Both historical and current studies suggest that if domestic work is included as productive work, the expanded labor force would contain about the same percentage of women as men. Estimates have been provided for the United States between 1800 and 1930 (Folbre & Wagman, 1993; Wagman & Folbre, forthcoming) and for India (World Bank, 1991: 14). Collection of more detailed data, accompanied by more concerted efforts to adjust historical statistics, could yield useful comparisons of cross-national differences in the changing composition of women’s employment.
79Revision of labor force statistics will require further development and institutionalization of time-use surveys. The length and intensity of work – whether in the market or in the home – is an important determinant of economic welfare that is omitted from standard consumption-based models (Floro, 1995). Most time-use surveys show that women tend to work much longer hours than men, particularly if they have small children. Hartmann (1981) summarizes several studies reporting this statistic for the United States. Duggan (1993) reports similar results from eastern and western Germany. The United Nations Development Program’s Human Development Report 1995 shows that in thirteen industrial countries women provided, on average, 51 percent of all labor hours, paid and unpaid (UNDP, 1995).
80Research in developing countries has suggested the same. Brown and Haddad (1994) report longer work days for women in seven countries in Asia and Africa. In Ghana teenage girls work longer weekly hours in both market and domestic work than boys, whether or not they are enrolled in school (Gage & Njogu, 1994). A UNDP (1995) analysis of nine developing countries found that women accounted for 53 percent of total labor hours.
81Since 1985 the World Bank has carried out several surveys designed to "get inside" the household: the Living Standards Measurement Study and the Social Dimensions of Adjustment series8. To date, however, gender analysis of these data has seldom extended beyond education and health (World Bank, 1995). The same may be said of many other household survey efforts.
Measuring the Importance of Nonlabor Inputs
82A third empirical problem concerns the paucity of efforts to measure the effect of nonlabor inputs, such as public and private investment, on the overall productivity of nonmarket production. For instance, what is the effect of greater provision of public utilities, such as water and gas, on the allocation of women’s time devoted to labor? How do improved consumer durables, such as more fuel-efficient cook stoves, affect family welfare? Does the provision of public daycare services increase women’s ability to provide other nonmarket services to enhance their families’ consumption, as well as their own participation in wage employment? Without empirical analysis of such questions it is impossible to apply the kinds of social cost-benefit criteria that are typically used to evaluate other types of public investment.
83Most macroeconomics texts allude to the fact that conventional definitions of GDP overstate the real rate of economic growth because they include additions to net product resulting from women’s entrance into wage employment but do not subtract the reduction in household production that normally occurs as a result. But conventional definitions may actually understate the rate of growth in industrial countries because improvements in the productivity of nonmarket work resulting from greater educational attainment and increased public or private capital investment may more than compensate.
84Trends in productivity and output in the nonmarket sector, which produces human capital and goods and services that are crucial components of the overall consumption bundle, do not necessarily follow trends in the market sector. Indeed, the two may be inversely related. Many gender and development scholars argue that structural adjustment policies that encourage shifts from production of nontradable to tradable goods have a negative impact on household production and family welfare. Like cutbacks in the provision of social services (health, education, and childcare) they increase demands on women’s labor time (Elson, 1991; Palmer, 1991; Cornia, Jolly & Stewart 1987).
85This result might not be deleterious if women’s time were underutilized (the assumption often made by policymakers unaware of actual patterns of time allocation). But many studies reveal unanticipated, adverse effects. Mothers may be forced to withdraw from paid employment or increase their demands on daughters to help with household tasks. Moser (1992) documents such behavior in low-income households in Guayaquil, Ecuador faced with a reduction in community services. Families maintained by women alone are particularly susceptible to such pressures. Tanski (1994, table 2) finds a significant increase in poverty among female-headed households in metropolitan Lima, Peru between 1985 and 1990.
86Short-term gains in measurable indicators, such as GDP or budget deficits, may be countervailed by long-run losses in less visible areas of economic output. The resulting macroeconomic distortions have negative consequences for women’s income, and welfare effects are exacerbated by the reduction of their bargaining power within the family (Kabeer, 1994; Klasen, 1993). It is difficult, if not impossible, to quantify these effects, given the lack of systematic survey data. And that is exactly the point: important policy issues cannot be addressed until macroeconomists concede the importance of monitoring and measuring nonmarket production.
Conclusion
87One of the most fascinating aspects of the development process is the way it has destabilized traditional patriarchal relations that once provided men with unquestioned power over women and children. A combination of technological change, social differentiation, and political struggle has increased individual autonomy, often with positive economic effects. But the shift away from family-based production toward labor markets based on individual wages has had some unanticipated negative effects on the organization of family life. As the costs of children have increased, mothers have borne the brunt of this growing economic burden, which is camouflaged by conventional measures of economic welfare.
88There is a lesson here for policy debates over privatization and reductions in social safety nets. Free markets may provide a good substitute for some previously state-run activities, but they do not provide much support for family life. Childrearing is no longer a remunerative activity, and both individuals and businesses that devote time and money to it will have a hard time competing with those who do not. Yet nonmarket work devoted to raising the next generation makes an enormous contribution to economic welfare, as does education. Children are public goods, and failure to collectively ensure their welfare and invest in their human capital will inevitably hamper economic growth.
89Many advocates for women in development emphasize the need for greater equality between men and women. But the process of economic development has taught us that it is easier to gain equal rights for women than to impose equal responsibilities for the care of children and other dependents on men. Some conservatives argue that women have become too powerful; their independence and self-assertion threatens the viability of the family. But it may be that women have simply not become powerful enough to persuade men, and society as a whole, to fairly share the costs of rearing the next generation.
90Future trends will depend, in large part, on forms of collective action that will redefine the role of the state, the family, and the firm. And these will depend, in turn, on how well economists, policymakers, and ordinary people understand the gradual but relentless realignment of the relationship between production and reproduction that is central to economic development. This is a process shaped by both conflict and cooperation, in which women will probably exert an increasingly collective influence.
Bibliographie
Des DOI sont automatiquement ajoutés aux références bibliographiques par Bilbo, l’outil d’annotation bibliographique d’OpenEdition. Ces références bibliographiques peuvent être téléchargées dans les formats APA, Chicago et MLA.
Format
- APA
- Chicago
- MLA
Abraham, Katharine, & Milan Vodopivec, Slovenia: A Study of Labor Market Transitions; World Bank, Policy Research Division, Transition Economics Division, Washington, D. C., 1993
Abu, K., “The Separateness of Spouses: Conjugal Resources in an Ashanti Town.” in Christine Oppong (ed.) Female and Male in West Africa, Allen and Unwin, London, 1983
10.4324/9781003402749 :Agarwal, Bina, “Gender and Command Over Property: A Critical Gap in Economic Analysis and Policy in South Asia.” World Development 22 (10): 1455 – 78, 1994a.
10.1016/0305-750X(94)90031-0 :Agarwal, Bina, “Positioning the Western Feminist Agenda: A Comment.”, Indian Journal of Gender Studies 1 (2): 249 – 56, 1994b
10.1177/097152159400100206 :Agarwal, Bina, A Field of One’s Own: Gender and Land Rights in South Asia, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1995
Alchian, A., & H. Demsetz, “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization.”, American Economic Review 62 (December): 777–95, 1972
10.1109/EMR.1975.4306431 :Alderman, Harold, Pierre-André Chiappori, Lawrence Haddad, John Hoddinott, & Ravi Kanbur, “Unitary Versus Collective Models of the Household: Is It Time to Shift the Burden of Proof?” World Bank Research Observer 10 (1): 1–19, 1995
10.1093/wbro/10.1.1 :Anker, Richard, & Catherine Hein, “Why Third World Urban Employers Usually Prefer Men.”, International Labour Review 124 (1): 73–90, 1985
Anker, Richard, & Catherine Hein, Sex Inequalities in Urban Employment in the Third World, St. Martin’s Press, New York, 1986
10.1007/978-1-349-18467-5 :Armstrong, Alice, “Maintenance Payments for Child Support in Southern Africa: Using Law to Promote Family Planning.” Studies in Family Planning 23 (4): 217–28, 1992
10.2307/1966884 :Barros, Ricardo, Louise Fox, & Rosane Mendonca, Female-Headed Households, Poverty, and the Welfare of Children in Urban Brazil, PC/ICRW Working Paper. The Population Council, New York, and the International Center for Research on Women, Washington, D. C., 1993
Becker, Gary S., A Treatise on the Family, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1981
10.2307/1973663 :Beller, Andrea H., “The Impact of Equal Opportunity Policy on Sex Differentials in Earnings and Occupations.”, American Economic Review 72 (2): 171–75, 1982
Beller, Andrea H., & John Graham, Small Change, The Economics of Child Support, Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1993
Bellmann, Lutz, Saul Estrin, Hartmut Lehmann, & Jonathan Wadsworth, Gross Flows in a Labour Market in Transition: Panel Data Estimates from Eastern Germany, London School of Economics Working Paper 173, London, 1992
Benería, Lourdes, “Conceptualizing the Labour Force: The Underestimation of Women’s Activities.”, Journal of Development Studies 17 (3): 10–27, l981
Benería, Lourdes, “Accounting for Women’s Work.” in Lourdes Benería (ed.) Women and Development: The Sexual Division of Labour in Rural Societies, Praeger, New York, 1982
Benería, Lourdes, “Accounting for Women’s Work: Assessing the Progress of Two Decades.”, World Development 20 (11): 1547–60, 1992
10.1016/0305-750X(92)90013-L :Benería, Lourdes, & Martha Roldán, The Crossroads of Class and Gender, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1987
Benería, Lourdes, & Gita Sen, “Accumulation, Reproduction, and Women’s Role in Economic Development: Boserup Revisited.”, Signs 7 (2): 279–98, 1981
10.1086/493882 :Bergmann, Barbara, The Economic Emergence of Women, Basic Books, New York, l986
10.1057/9781403982582 :Birdsall, Nancy, & Richard Sabot (eds.), Unfair Advantage: Labor Market Discrimination in Developing Countries, World Bank, Washington, D. C., 1991
Blackden, C. Mark, & E. Morris-Hughes, Paradigm Postponed: Gender and Economic Adjustment in Sub-Saharan Africa, Technical Note 13, World Bank, Africa Region, Human Resources and Poverty Division, Washington, D. C., 1993
Blumberg, Rae Lesser, Making the Case for the Gender Variable: Women and the Wealth and Well-Being of Nations, U. S. Agency for International Development, Office of Women in Development, Washington, D. C., 1989
Bolles, Lynn, “Economic Crisis and Female-Headed Households in Urban Jamaica.” in June Nash and Helen Safa (eds.) Women and Change in Latin America, Bergin and Garvey, South Hadley, Mass., l986
Boserup, Ester, Women’s Role in Economic Development, Allen and Unwin, London, 1970
Boserup, Ester, “Obstacles to Advancement of Women During Development.” in T. Paul Schultz (ed.), Investment in Women’s Human Capital and Economic Development, Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1993
Brachet-Marquez, V., Absentee Fathers: A Case-Based Study of Family Law and Child Welfare in Mexico, PC/ICRW Working Paper, Population Council, New York, and the International Center for Research on Women, Washington, D. C., 1992
Brown, Lynn R., & Lawrence Haddad, Time Allocation Patterns and Time Burdens: A Gendered Analysis of Seven Countries, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C., 1994
Bruce, Judith, & Cynthia Lloyd, Families in Focus, The Population Council, New York, Forthcoming
Buchanan, James, “Profit Seeking and Rent Seeking.” in James Buchanan, Robert Tollison, & Gordon Tullock, (eds.), Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, Texas A & M University Press, College Station, Tex., 1980
10.1007/978-3-540-79182-9 :Buvinic, Mayra, Margaret Lycette, & William Paul McGreevey, Women and Poverty in the Third World, Johns Hopkins University PressBaltimore, Md., 1983
Buvinic, Mayra, J. P. Valenzuela, T. Molina, & E. Gonzales, “The Fortunes of Adolescent Mothers and Their Children: The Transmission of Poverty in Santiago, Chile.”, Population and Development Review 18 (2): 269 – 97, 1992
10.2307/1973680 :Caldwell, John, The Theory of Fertility Decline, Academic Press, New York, l982
Caldwell, John, & Pat Caldwell, “The Cultural Context of High Fertility in Sub-Saharan Africa.”, Population and Development Review 13 (3): 409–38, l987
10.2307/1973133 :Chant, Sylvia, Women and Survival in Mexican Cities: Perspectives on Gender, Labour Markets, and Low-Income Households, Manchester University Press, New York, 1991
Cheater, Angela, “Women and Their Participation in Commercial Agricultural Production: The Case of Medium-Scale Freehold in Zimbabwe.”, Development and Change 12 (3): 349–77, 1981
10.1111/j.1467-7660.1981.tb00805.x :Coase, Ronald, “The Problem of Social Cost.”, Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1): 529–46, 1960
10.1086/466560 :Commander, Simon, Leonid Liberman, & Rusland Yemtsov, Wage and Employment Decisions in the Russian Economy: An Analysis of Developments in 1992, World Bank, Institute for Economic Forecasting, Russian Academy of Sciences, and Moscow State University, Washington, D. C., 1993
Cornia, G. A., R. Jolly, & F. Stewart (eds.), Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth, Oxford University Press, New York, 1987
Deere, Carmen Diana, “What Difference Does Gender Make? Rethinking Peasant Studies.”, Feminist Economics 1 (1): 53 – 57, 1995
10.1080/714042214 :Deere, Carmen Diana, & Magdalena León (eds.), Rural Women and State Policy: Feminist Perspectives on Latin American Agricultural Development, Westview Press, Boulder, Colo., 1987
10.4324/9780429305184 :Desai, Sonalde, Children at Risk: The Role of Family Structure in Latin America and West Africa, Working Paper 28, The Population Council, New York, 1991
10.2307/1973760 :Duggan, Lynn, Production and Reproduction: Family Policy and Gender Inequality in East and West Germany, Unpublished Ph. D. dissertation, University of Massachusetts at Amherst, Department of Economics, 1993
Dwyer, Daisy, & Judith Bruce (eds.), A Home Divided: Women and Income in the Third World, Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif., 1988
10.2307/1973637 :Eisner, Robert, The Total Incomes System of Accounts, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, l989
Elson, Diane, Male Bias in the Development Process, Manchester University Press, Manchester, UK, 1991
Elson, Diane, “From Survival Strategies to Transformation Strategies: Women’s Needs and Structural Adjustment.”, in Lourdes Benería and Shelley Feldman, (eds.), Unequal Burden: Economic Crises, Persistent Poverty, and Women’s Work, Westview Press, Boulder, Colo., 1992
Engle, Patrice L., & Cynthia Breaux, Is There a Father Instinct? Fathers’ Responsibility for Children, PC/ICRW Working Paper. Population Council, New York, and International Center for Research on Women, Washington, D. C., 1994
Floro, Maria, “Women’s Well-Being, Poverty, and Work Intensity.”, Feminist Economics 1 (3): 1–25, 1995
10.1080/714042246 :Fogel, Robert William, & Stanley L. Engerman, Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, Little, Brown, and Company, Boston, 1974
Folbre, Nancy, “Women on Their Own: Global Patterns of Female Headship.” in Rita S. Gallin & Ann Ferguson (eds.), Women and International Development, Annual Vol. 2., Westview, Boulder, Colo., 1990
10.4324/9780367274566 :Folbre, Nancy, “The Unproductive Housewife: Her Evolution in Nineteenth Century Economic Thought.”, Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society 16(3): 463–84, 1991
10.1086/494679 :Folbre, Nancy, “Guys Don’t Do That: Gender Groups and Social Norms.”, paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Economic Association, Anaheim, California, December 1993a
Folbre, Nancy, Women and Social Security in Latin America, the Caribbean, and Sub-Saharan Africa, Working Paper 5. International Labour Office, Equality For Women in Employment: An Interdepartmental Project, Geneva, 1993b
Folbre, Nancy, Who Pays for the Kids? Gender and the Structures of Constraint, Routledge, New York, 1994
Folbre, Nancy, & Marjorie Abel, “Women’s Work and Women’s Households: Gender Bias in the U. S. Census.”, Social Research 56 (3): 545–70, 1989
Folbre, Nancy, & Barnet Wagman, “Counting Housework: New Estimates of Real Product in the U. S., 1800 – 1860.”, Journal of Economic History 53 (2): 275–88, 1993
Fong, Monica, & Gillian Paul, “Women’s Employment in Central and Eastern Europe: The Gender Factor.”, Transition 3 (6): 1 – 3, 1992
Fuchs, Victor, Women’s Quest for Economic Equality, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1988
10.1257/jep.3.1.25 :Gage, Anastasia J., & Wamucii Njogu, Ghana/Kenya: Gender Inequalities and Demographic Behavior, New York: The Population Council, 1994
Glendon, Mary Ann, The Transformation of Family Law: State, Law, and Family in the United States and Western Europe, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, l989
Goldin, Claudia, Understanding the Gender Gap, Oxford University Press, Oxford, l990
Goldschmidt-Clermont, Luisella, Unpaid Work in the Household, International Labour Office, Geneva, 1982
Goode, William J., World Changes in Divorce Patterns, Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1993
Haddad, Lawrence, & Ravi Kanbur, “Intrahousehold Inequality and the Theory of Targeting.”, European Economic Review 36 (2/3): 372–78, 1992
10.1016/0014-2921(92)90093-C :Haddad, Lawrence, & Thomas Reardon, “Gender Bias in the Allocation of Resources Within Households in Burkina Faso: A Disaggregated Outlay Equivalent Analysis.”, Journal of Development Studies 29 (2): 260 – 76, 1993
10.1080/00220389308422273 :Ham, John, Jan Svejnar, & Katherine Terrell, “Czech Republic and Slovakia.” in Simon Commander & Fabrizio Coricelli (eds.), Unemployment, Restructuring, and the Labor Market in Eastern Europe and Russia, World Bank, Washington, D. C., 1995
Hartmann, Heidi, “The Family as a Locus of Gender, Class, and Political Struggle.”, Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society 6 (3): 366 – 94, 1981
Heise, Lori L., Jacqueline Pitanguy, & Adrienne Germain, Violence Against Women: The Hidden Health Burden, World Bank Discussion Paper 255, Washington, D. C., 1994
10.1177/1077801298004003002 :Hoddinott, John, “Rotten Kids or Manipulative Parents: Are Children Old Age Security in Western Kenya?”, Economic Development and Cultural Change 40 (3): 545–65, 1992
10.1086/451960 :Hoddinott, John, Howard Alderman, & Lawrence Haddad, “Household Models and Intrahousehold Resource Allocation.” in John Hoddinott, Lawrence Haddad, & Howard Alderman (eds.), Intrahousehold Resource Allocation in Developing Countries: Methods, Models, and Policy, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Md., Forthcoming
Hodgson, Geoffry, Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics, University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, 1987
Holt, Sharon, & Helena Ribe, Developing Financial Institutions for the Poor and Reducing Barriers to Access for Women, World Bank Discussion Paper 118, Washington, D. C., 1991
Joekes, Susan, Women in the World Economy, Oxford University Press, New York, 1987
Kabeer, Naila, Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought, Verso, London, 1994
Kardam, N., “The Adaptability of International Development Agencies: The Response of the World Bank to Women in Development.” in K. Staudt (ed.), Women, International Development, and Politics, Temple University Press, Philadelphia, Penn., 1990
Katzman, R., “Why Are Men So Irresponsible?”, CEPAL Review 46: 79–87.
Kerr, Joanna, Ours by Right: Women’s Rights as Human Rights, Zed Books, London, 1992
King, Elizabeth M., & M. Anne Hill, Women’s Education in Developing Countries: Barriers, Benefits, and Policies, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Md., 1993
10.1093/acrefore/9780199381135.013.6892 :Klasen, Stephen, Gender Inequality and Development Strategies: Lessons from the Past and Policy Issues for the Future, Working Paper 41, International Labour Office, World Employment Programme Research, Geneva, 1993
Knight, Jack, Institutions and Social Conflict, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1992
10.1017/CBO9780511528170 :Koussoudji, Sherrie, & Eva Mueller, “The Economic and Demographic Status of Female-Headed Households.”, Economic Development and Cultural Change 31 (4): 831–59, 1983
Krueger, Anne O., “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society.”, American Economic Review 64 (3): 291–303, 1974
10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5 :Levin, Bozena, “Unemployment Among Polish Women.”, Comparative Economic Studies 35 (4): 135–45, 1993
10.1057/ces.1993.42 :Libecap, Gary, Contracting for Property Rights, Cambridge University Press, New York, 1989
10.1017/CBO9780511664120 :Lloyd, Cynthia B., & Anastasia J. Gage-Brandon, “Women’s Role in Maintaining Households: Family Welfare and Sexual Inequality in Ghana.”, Population Studies 47(1): 115–31, 1993
10.1080/0032472031000146766 :Louat, Frederic, Margaret Grosh, & Jacques van der Gaag, “Welfare Implications of Female Headship in Jamaican Households.”, paper presented at the Intrahousehold resource allo - cation conference: policy issues and research methods, International Food and Policy Research Institute – World Bank, February 12 – 14, Washington, D. C., 1992
Lucas, Robert E. B., & Oded Stark, “Motivations to Remit: Evidence from Botswana.”, Journal of Political Economy 93 (5): 901–18, 1985
Lundberg, Shelley, & Robert A. Pollak, “Separate Spheres Bargaining and the Marriage Market.”, Journal of Political Economy 101 (6): 988–1010, 1993
10.1086/261912 :Maier, Friederike, “The Labour Market for Women and Employment Perspectives in the Aftermath of German Unification.”, Cambridge Journal of Economics 17 (3): 267–80, 1993
Martin, Doris M., & Fatuma Omar Hashi, Gender, the Evolution of Legal Institutions, and Economic Development in Sub – Saharan Africa, Working Paper 3. World Bank, Africa Region, Poverty and Social Policy Division, Technical Department, Washington, D. C., 1992a
Martin, Doris M., & Fatuma Omar Hashi, Law as an Institutional Barrier to the Economic Empowerment of Women, Working Paper 2. World Bank, Africa Region, Poverty and Social Policy Division, Technical Department, Washington, D. C., 1992b
Martin, Doris M., & Fatuma Omar Hashi, Women in Development: The Legal Issues in Sub-Saharan Africa Today, Working Paper 4. World Bank Africa Region, Poverty and Social Policy Division, Technical Department, Washington, D. C., 1992c
McElroy, Marjorie, “The Empirical Content of Nash-Bargained Household Behavior.”, Journal of Human Resources 25 (4): 559–83, 1990
10.2307/145667 :Mohanty, Chandra Talpade, “Under Western Eyes: Feminist Scholarship and Colonial Discourses.” in Chandra Talpade Mohanty, Ann Russo, & Lourdes Torres (eds.), Third World Women and the Politics of Feminism, Indiana University Press, Bloomington, Ind., 1991
10.1057/fr.1988.42 :Morgan, Robin, Sisterhood Is Global, Anchor Books, Garden City, N. Y., 1984
Moser, Caroline, “Adjustment from Below: Low-Income Women, Time, and the Triple Burden in Guayaquil, Ecuador.” in H. Ashfar & C. Dennis (eds.), Women and Adjustment Policies in the Third World, St. Martin’s Press, New York, 1992
Moser, Caroline, Gender Planning and Development: Theory, Practice, and Training, Routledge, New York, 1993
10.4324/9780203411940 :Munachonga, Monica, “Income Allocation and Marriage Options in Urban Zambia.” in Daisy Dwyer & Judith Bruce (eds.), A Home Divided: Women and Income in the Third World, Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif., 1988
10.1515/9780804765824 :North, Douglass, Structure and Change in Economic History, Norton, New York, 1981
North, Douglass, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1990
10.1017/CBO9780511808678 :Olson, Mancur, The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1982
Orazem, Peter, & Milan Vodopivec, Winners and Losers in Transition: Returns to Education, Experience, and Gender in Slovenia, Policy Research Working Paper 1342, World Bank, Policy Research Department, Transition Economics Division, Washington, D.C., 1994
Palmer, Ingrid, Gender and Population in the Adjustment of African Economics: Planning for Change, International Labor Office, Geneva, 1991
Psacharopoulos, George, & Zafiris Tzannatos (eds.), Case Studies on Women’s Employment and Pay in Latin America, World Bank, Washington, D. C., 1992
Pyle, Jean Larson, The State and Women in the Economy: Lessons from Sex Discrimination in the Republic of Ireland, State University of New York Press, New York, 1990
Ramirez, Carmen O., La mujer: Su situación jurídica in veintiseis países americanos, Marcos Lerner, Cordoba, Argentina, 1987
Rogers, B., The Domestication of Women: Discrimination in Developing Societies, Kogan Page, London, 1980
10.4324/9780203974384 :Rosenzweig, Mark R., & T. Paul Schultz, “Market Opportunities, Genetic Endowments, and Intrafamily Resource Distribution: Child Survival in Rural India.”, American Economic Review 72 (4): 803–15, 1982
Safilios-Rothschild, Constantina, “The Impact of Agrarian Reform on Men’s and Women’s Incomes in Rural Honduras.” in Daisy Dwyer & Judith Bruce (eds.), A Home Divided: Women and Income in the Third World, Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif., l988
Schotter, Andrew, The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1981
10.1017/CBO9780511983863 :Schultz, T. Paul, “Testing the Neoclassical Model of Family Labor Supply and Fertility.”, Journal of Human Resources 25 (4): 599–634, 1990
10.2307/145669 :Schultz, T. Paul, “Introduction.” in T. Paul Schultz (ed.), Investment in Women’s Human Capital and Economic Development, Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1993
10.2753/PIN1099-9922160401 :Seguino, Stephanie, Gender Wage Discrimination and Export-Led Growth in South Korea, American University, Department of Economics, Washington, D. C., 1994
Sen, Amartya, “Family and Food: Sex Bias in Poverty.” in T. N. Srinivasan & Pranab Bardhan (eds.), Rural Poverty in South Asia, Columbia University Press, New York, 1988
Sen, Amartya, “Gender and Cooperative Conflicts.” in Irene Tinker (ed.), Persistent Inequalities: Women and World Development, Oxford University Press, New York, 1990
Sen, Gita, & Caren Grown, Development, Crises, and Alternative Visions: Third World Women’s Perspectives, Monthly Review Press, New York, 1987
10.2307/1967063 :Staudt, Kathleen, “Agricultural Productivity Gaps: A Case Study of Male Preference in Government Policy Implementation.”, Development and Change 9 (3): 439–57, 1978
10.1111/j.1467-7660.1978.tb00771.x :Subbarao, K., & Laura Raney, Social Gains from Female Education: A Cross-National Study, World Bank Discussion Paper 194, Washington, D. C., 1993
10.1596/r11 :Tanski, Janet, “The Impact of Crisis, Stabilization, and Structural Adjustment on Women in Lima, Peru.”, World Development 22 (11): 1627–42, 1994
10.1016/0305-750X(94)00073-5 :Tauchen, Helen V., Ann Dryden Witte & Sharon K. Long, “Domestic Violence: A Nonrandom Affair.”, International Economic Review 32 (2): 491–511, 1991
10.2307/2526888 :Thomas, Duncan, “Intra-Household Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach.”, Journal of Human Resources 25 (4): 635 – 64, 1990
10.2307/145670 :UNDP (United Nations Development Programme), Human Development Report 1995, Oxford University Press, New York, 1995
10.18356/6d252f18-en :Wagman, Barnet, & Nancy Folbre, “Household Services and Economic Growth in the United States, 1870 – 1930.”, Feminist Economics, Forthcoming
Waring, Marilyn, If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics, Harper and Row, New York, 1988
Williamson, Oliver, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, Free Press, New York, 1985
Williamson, Oliver, “The Institutions and Governance of Economic Development and Reform.” in Michael Bruno & Boris Pleskovic (eds.), Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, World Bank, Washington, D. C., 1995
10.1093/wber/8.suppl_1.171 :Winter, Carolyn, “Gender Discrimination in the Labor Market and the Role of the Law: Experiences in Six Latin American Countries.”, World Bank, Latin America and the Caribbean Technical Department, Washington, D. C., 1994
World Bank, Gender and Poverty in India, Washington, D. C., 1991
World Bank, Enhancing Women’s Participation in Economic Development, A World Bank Policy Paper, Washington, D. C., 1994
World Bank, Gender and Development: Equity and Efficiency, Poverty and Social Policy Department, Gender Analysis and Policy, Washington, D. C., 1995
Wyss, Brenda, Gender and the Economic Support of Jamaican Households: Implications for Children’s Living Standards, Unpublished Ph. D. dissertation. University of Massachusetts at Amherst, Department of Economics, Amherst, Mass., 1995
Notes de bas de page
1 The most recent examples of publications by multilateral institutions include World Bank (1994) and Klasen (1993). In addition, both the World Bank and the office of the United Nations Development Program’s Human Development Report prepared reports on gender issues for the International Women’s Conference in Beijing in September 1995.
2 Boserup’s more recent work does not fit neatly into the women in development category. She writes that “men’s interest in preserving the traditional ranking order between the sexes should not be underestimated in any analysis of women’s position; it should not be overestimated either” (1993, p. 2).
3 A more explicit definition is given by Andrew Schotter: “A regularity in social behavior that is agreed to by all members of society, specifies behavior in specific recurrent situations, and is either self-policed or policed by some external authority” (1981, p. 11). This definition, however, virtually precludes the possibility that some groups impose social institutions on others.
4 In what I consider the best chapter of The Rise and Decline of Nations, chapter 6, Olson does consider racial and caste groups. But he does not devote much attention to the difference between voluntary and involuntary groups. For a slightly more detailed discussion of this issue, see Folbre (1993a).
5 This argument is distinct from that developed by Becker (1981) in his Rotten Kid Theorem because it emphasizes that the seemingly altruistic behavior of the male head of household is partially motivated by individual self-interest (in Becker’s model, pure altruism rules). Note the similarity with Fogel and Engerman’s (1974) classic argument regarding the economic effects of slavery in the United States. Despite their political and personal oppression, slaves may have been relatively well-fed and housed because they were such important factors of production. Their standard of living may have fallen immediately after emancipation because of their lack of access to land.
6 For a discussion of how changes in access to common property resources might affect household distribution, see Haddad and Kanbur (1992).
7 While the World Bank Living Standards Measurement Survey of Jamaica collected data on remittances, it did not specifically ascertain which parents were remitting sums for which children (Wyss 1995).
8 Countries surveyed by Living Standards Measurement Studies include Bolivia, Cote d’Ivoire, Ecuador, Ghana, Guyana, Jamaica, the Kyrgyz Republic, Mauritania, Morocco, Nicaragua, Pakistan, Peru, Romania, Russia, South Africa, Tanzania, Venezuela, and Viet Nam. Social Dimensions of Adjustment surveys are available for Burkina Faso, Burundi, Central African Republic, Chad, Cote d’Ivoire, The Gambia, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Mali, Mauritania, Senegal, and Zambia.
Auteur
Professor of Economics, University of Massachussetts, USA.
Le texte seul est utilisable sous licence Creative Commons - Attribution - Pas d'Utilisation Commerciale - Pas de Modification 4.0 International - CC BY-NC-ND 4.0. Les autres éléments (illustrations, fichiers annexes importés) sont « Tous droits réservés », sauf mention contraire.
Les silences pudiques de l'économie
Économie et rapports sociaux entre hommes et femmes
Yvonne Preiswerk et Anne Zwahlen (dir.)
1998
Tant qu’on a la santé
Les déterminants socio-économiques et culturels de la santé dans les relations sociales entre les femmes et les hommes
Yvonne Preiswerk et Mary-Josée Burnier (dir.)
1999
Quel genre d’homme ?
Construction sociale de la masculinité, relations de genre et développement
Christine Verschuur (dir.)
2000
Hommes armés, femmes aguerries
Rapports de genre en situations de conflit armé
Fenneke Reysoo (dir.)
2001
On m'appelle à régner
Mondialisation, pouvoirs et rapports de genre
Fenneke Reysoo et Christine Verschuur (dir.)
2003
Femmes en mouvement
Genre, migrations et nouvelle division internationale du travail
Fenneke Reysoo et Christine Verschuur (dir.)
2004
Vents d'Est, vents d'Ouest
Mouvements de femmes et féminismes anticoloniaux
Christine Verschuur (dir.)
2009
Chic, chèque, choc
Transactions autour des corps et stratégies amoureuses contemporaines
Françoise Grange Omokaro et Fenneke Reysoo (dir.)
2012
Des brèches dans la ville
Organisations urbaines, environnement et transformation des rapports de genre
Christine Verschuur et François Hainard (dir.)
2006